Corante

About this Author
DBL%20Hendrix%20small.png College chemistry, 1983

Derek Lowe The 2002 Model

Dbl%20new%20portrait%20B%26W.png After 10 years of blogging. . .

Derek Lowe, an Arkansan by birth, got his BA from Hendrix College and his PhD in organic chemistry from Duke before spending time in Germany on a Humboldt Fellowship on his post-doc. He's worked for several major pharmaceutical companies since 1989 on drug discovery projects against schizophrenia, Alzheimer's, diabetes, osteoporosis and other diseases. To contact Derek email him directly: derekb.lowe@gmail.com Twitter: Dereklowe

Chemistry and Drug Data: Drugbank
Emolecules
ChemSpider
Chempedia Lab
Synthetic Pages
Organic Chemistry Portal
PubChem
Not Voodoo
DailyMed
Druglib
Clinicaltrials.gov

Chemistry and Pharma Blogs:
Org Prep Daily
The Haystack
Kilomentor
A New Merck, Reviewed
Liberal Arts Chemistry
Electron Pusher
All Things Metathesis
C&E News Blogs
Chemiotics II
Chemical Space
Noel O'Blog
In Vivo Blog
Terra Sigilatta
BBSRC/Douglas Kell
ChemBark
Realizations in Biostatistics
Chemjobber
Pharmalot
ChemSpider Blog
Pharmagossip
Med-Chemist
Organic Chem - Education & Industry
Pharma Strategy Blog
No Name No Slogan
Practical Fragments
SimBioSys
The Curious Wavefunction
Natural Product Man
Fragment Literature
Chemistry World Blog
Synthetic Nature
Chemistry Blog
Synthesizing Ideas
Business|Bytes|Genes|Molecules
Eye on FDA
Chemical Forums
Depth-First
Symyx Blog
Sceptical Chymist
Lamentations on Chemistry
Computational Organic Chemistry
Mining Drugs
Henry Rzepa


Science Blogs and News:
Bad Science
The Loom
Uncertain Principles
Fierce Biotech
Blogs for Industry
Omics! Omics!
Young Female Scientist
Notional Slurry
Nobel Intent
SciTech Daily
Science Blog
FuturePundit
Aetiology
Gene Expression (I)
Gene Expression (II)
Sciencebase
Pharyngula
Adventures in Ethics and Science
Transterrestrial Musings
Slashdot Science
Cosmic Variance
Biology News Net


Medical Blogs
DB's Medical Rants
Science-Based Medicine
GruntDoc
Respectful Insolence
Diabetes Mine


Economics and Business
Marginal Revolution
The Volokh Conspiracy
Knowledge Problem


Politics / Current Events
Virginia Postrel
Instapundit
Belmont Club
Mickey Kaus


Belles Lettres
Uncouth Reflections
Arts and Letters Daily
In the Pipeline: Don't miss Derek Lowe's excellent commentary on drug discovery and the pharma industry in general at In the Pipeline

In the Pipeline

« Closure at the Neurosciences Institute? | Main | Making Tumor Cells More Vigorous Through. . .Chemotherapy? »

August 9, 2012

Getting Drug Research Really, Really Wrong

Email This Entry

Posted by Derek

The British Medical Journal says that the "widely touted innovation crisis in pharmaceuticals is a myth". The British Medical Journal is wrong.

There, that's about as direct as I can make it. But allow me to go into more detail, because that's not the the only thing they're wrong about. This is a new article entitled "Pharmaceutical research and development: what do we get for all that money?", and it's by Joel Lexchin (York University) and Donald Light of UMDNJ. And that last name should be enough to tell you where this is all coming from, because Prof. Light is the man who's publicly attached his name to an estimate that developing a new drug costs about $43 million dollars.

I'm generally careful, when I bring up that figure around people who actually develop drugs, not to do so when they're in the middle of drinking coffee or working with anything fragile, because it always provokes startled expressions and sudden laughter. These posts go into some detail about how ludicrous that number is, but for now, I'll just note that it's hard to see how anyone who seriously advances that estimate can be taken seriously. But here we are again.

Light and Lexchin's article makes much of Bernard Munos' work (which we talked about here), which shows a relatively constant rate of new drug discovery. They should go back and look at his graph, because they might notice that the slope of the line in recent years has not kept up with the historical rate. And they completely leave out one of the other key points that Munos makes: that even if the rate of discovery were to have remained linear, the costs associated with it sure as hell haven't. No, it's all a conspiracy:

"Meanwhile, telling "innovation crisis" stories to politicians and the press serves as a ploy, a strategy to attract a range of government protections from free market, generic competition."

Ah, that must be why the industry has laid off thousands and thousands of people over the last few years: it's all a ploy to gain sympathy. We tell everyone else how hard it is to discover drugs, but when we're sure that there are no reporters or politicians around, we high-five each other at how successful our deception has been. Because that's our secret, according to Light and Lexchin. It's apparently not any harder to find something new and worthwhile, but we'd rather just sit on our rears and crank out "me-too" medications for the big bucks:

"This is the real innovation crisis: pharmaceutical research and development turns out mostly minor variations on existing drugs, and most new drugs are not superior on clinical measures. Although a steady stream of significantly superior drugs enlarges the medicine chest from which millions benefit, medicines have also produced an epidemic of serious adverse reactions that have added to national healthcare costs".

So let me get this straight: according to these folks, we mostly just make "minor variations", but the few really new drugs that come out aren't so great either, because of their "epidemic" of serious side effects. Let me advance an alternate set of explanations, one that I call, for lack of a better word, "reality". For one thing, "me-too" drugs are not identical, and their benefits are often overlooked by people who do not understand medicine. There are overcrowded therapeutic areas, but they're not common. The reason that some new drugs make only small advances on existing therapies is not because we like it that way, and it's especially not because we planned it that way. This happens because we try to make big advances, and we fail. Then we take what we can get.

No therapeutic area illustrates this better than oncology. Every new target in that field has come in with high hopes that this time we'll have something that really does the job. Angiogenesis inhibitors. Kinase inhibitors. Cell cycle disruptors. Microtubules, proteosomes, apoptosis, DNA repair, metabolic disruption of the Warburg effect. It goes on and on and on, and you know what? None of them work as well as we want them to. We take them into the clinic, give them to terrified people who have little hope left, and we watch as we provide with them, what? A few months of extra life? Was that what we were shooting for all along, do we grin and shake each others' hands when the results come in? "Another incremental advance! Rock and roll!"

Of course not. We're disappointed, and we're pissed off. But we don't know enough about cancer (yet) to do better, and cancer turns out to be a very hard condition to treat. It should also be noted that the financial incentives are there to discover something that really does pull people back from the edge of the grave, so you'd think that we money-grubbing, public-deceiving, expense-padding mercenaries might be attracted by that prospect. Apparently not.

The same goes for Alzheimer's disease. Just how much money has the industry spent over the last quarter of a century on Alzheimer's? I worked on it twenty years ago, and God knows that never came to anything. Look at the steady march, march, march of failure in the clinic - and keep in mind that these failures tend to come late in the game, during Phase III, and if you suggest to anyone in the business that you can run an Alzheimer's Phase III program and bring the whole thing in for $43 million dollars, you'll be invited to stop wasting everyone's time. Bapineuzumab's trials have surely cost several times that, and Pfizer/J&J are still pressing on. And before that you had Elan working on active immunization, which is still going on, and you have Lilly's other antibody, which is still going on, and Genentech's (which is still going on). No one has high hopes for any of these, but we're still burning piles of money to try to find something. And what about the secretase inhibitors? How much time and effort has gone into beta- and gamma-secretase? What did the folks at Lilly think when they took their inhibitor way into Phase III only to find out that it made Alzheimer's slightly worse instead of helping anyone? Didn't they realize that Professors Light and Lexchin were on to them? That they'd seen through the veil and figured out the real strategy of making tiny improvements on the existing drugs that attack the causes of Alzheimer's? What existing drugs to target the causes of Alzheimer are they talking about?

Honestly, I have trouble writing about this sort of thing, because I get too furious to be coherent. I've been doing this sort of work since 1989, and I have spent the great majority of my time working on diseases for which no good therapies existed. The rest of the time has been spent on new mechanisms, new classes of drugs that should (or should have) worked differently than the existing therapies. I cannot recall a time when I have worked on a real "me-too" drug of the sort of that Light and Lexchin seem to think the industry spends all its time on.

That's because of yet another factor they have not considered: simultaneous development. Take a look at that paragraph above, where I mentioned all those Alzheimer's therapies. Let's be wildly, crazily optimistic and pretend that bapineuzumab manages to eke out some sort of efficacy against Alzheimer's (which, by the way, would put it right into that "no real medical advance" category that Light and Lexchin make so much of). And let's throw caution out the third-floor window and pretend that Lilly's solanezumab actually does something, too. Not much - there's a limit to how optimistic a person can be without pharmacological assistance - but something, some actual efficacy. Now here's what you have to remember: according to people like the authors of this article, whichever of these antibodies that makes it though second is a "me-too" drug that offers only an incremental advance, if anything. Even though all this Alzheimer's work was started on a risk basis, in several different companies, with different antibodies developed in different ways, with no clue as to who (if anyone) might come out on top.

All right, now we get to another topic that articles like this latest one are simply not complete without. That's right, say it together: "Drug companies spend a lot more on marketing than they do on research!" Let's ignore, for the sake of argument, the large number of smaller companies that spend all of their money on R&D and none on marketing, because they have nothing to market yet. Let's even ignore the fact that over the years, the percentage of money being spent on drug R&D has actually been going up. No, let's instead go over this in a way that even professors at UMDNJ and York can understand it:

Company X spends, let's say, $10 a year on research. (We're lopping off a lot of zeros to make this easier). It has no revenues from selling drugs yet, and is burning through its cash while it tries to get its first on onto the market. It succeeds, and the new drug will bring in $100 dollars a year for the first two or three years, before the competition catches up with some of the incremental me-toos that everyone will switch to for mysterious reasons that apparently have nothing to do with anything working better. But I digress; let's get back to the key point. That $100 a year figure assumes that the company spends $30 a year on marketing (advertising, promotion, patient awareness, brand-building, all that stuff). If the company does not spend all that time and effort, the new drug will only bring in $60 a year, but that's pure profit. (We're going to ignore all the other costs, assuming that they're the same between the two cases).

So the company can bring in $60 dollars a year by doing no promotion, or it can bring in $70 a year after accounting for the expenses of marketing. The company will, of course, choose the latter. "But," you're saying, "what if all that marketing expense doesn't raise sales from $60 up to $100 a year?" Ah, then you are doing it wrong. The whole point, the raison d'etre of the marketing department is to bring in more money than they are spending. Marketing deals with the profitable side of the business; their job is to maximize those profits. If they spend more than those extra profits, well, it's time to fire them, isn't it?

R&D, on the other hand, is not the profitable side of the business. Far from it. We are black holes of finance: huge sums of money spiral in beyond our event horizons, emitting piteous cries and futile streams of braking radiation, and are never seen again. The point is, these are totally different parts of the company, doing totally different things. Complaining that the marketing budget is bigger than the R&D budget is like complaining that a car's passenger compartment is bigger than its gas tank, or that a ship's sail is bigger than its rudder.

OK, I've spend about enough time on this for one morning; I feel like I need a shower. Let's get on to the part where Light and Lexchin recommend what we should all be doing instead:

What can be done to change the business model of the pharmaceutical industry to focus on more cost effective, safer medicines? The first step should be to stop approving so many new drugs of little therapeutic value. . .We should also fully fund the EMA and other regulatory agencies with public funds, rather than relying on industry generated user fees, to end industry’s capture of its regulator. Finally, we should consider new ways of rewarding innovation directly, such as through the large cash prizes envisioned in US Senate Bill 1137, rather than through the high prices generated by patent protection. The bill proposes the collection of several billion dollars a year from all federal and non-federal health reimbursement and insurance programmes, and a committee would award prizes in proportion to how well new drugs fulfilled unmet clinical needs and constituted real therapeutic gains. Without patents new drugs are immediately open to generic competition, lowering prices, while at the same time innovators are rewarded quickly to innovate again. This approach would save countries billions in healthcare costs and produce real gains in people’s health.

One problem I have with this is that the health insurance industry would probably object to having "several billion dollars a year" collected from it. And that "several" would not mean "two or three", for sure. But even if we extract that cash somehow - an extraction that would surely raise health insurance costs as it got passed along - we now find ourselves depending on a committee that will determine the worth of each new drug. Will these people determine that when the drug is approved, or will they need to wait a few years to see how it does in the real world? If the drug under- or overperforms, does the reward get adjusted accordingly? How, exactly, do we decide how much a diabetes drug is worth compared to one for multiple sclerosis, or TB? What about a drug that doesn't help many people, but helps them tremendously, versus a drug that's taken by a lot of people, but has only milder improvements for them? What if a drug is worth a lot more to people in one demographic versus another? And what happens as various advocacy groups lobby to get their diseases moved further up the list of important ones that deserve higher prizes and more incentives?

These will have to be some very, very wise and prudent people on this committee. You certainly wouldn't want anyone who's ever been involved with the drug industry on there, no indeed. And you wouldn't want any politicians - why, they might use that influential position to do who knows what. No, you'd want honest, intelligent, reliable people, who know a tremendous amount about medical care and pharmaceuticals, but have no financial or personal interests involved. I'm sure there are plenty of them out there, somewhere. And when we find them, why stop with drugs? Why not set up committees to determine the true worth of the other vital things that people in this country need each day - food, transportation, consumer goods? Surely this model can be extended; it all sounds so rational. I doubt if anything like it has ever been tried before, and it's certainly a lot better than the grubby business of deciding prices and values based on what people will pay for things (what do they know, anyway, compared to a panel of dispassionate experts?)

Enough. I should mention that when Prof. Light's earlier figure for drug expense came out that I had a brief correspondence with him, and I invited him to come to this site and try out his reasoning on people who develop drugs for a living. Communication seemed to dry up after that, I have to report. But that offer is still open. Reading his publications makes me think that he (and his co-authors) have never actually spoken with anyone who does this work or has any actual experience with it. Come on down, I say! We're real people, just like you. OK, we're more evil, fine. But otherwise. . .

Comments (74) + TrackBacks (0) | Category: "Me Too" Drugs | Business and Markets | Cancer | Drug Development | Drug Industry History | Drug Prices | The Central Nervous System | Why Everyone Loves Us


COMMENTS

1. PorkPieHat on August 9, 2012 11:45 AM writes...

Whew, what a doozy. This got published in the British Medical Journal. Who's reviewing this sort of publication, anyway? How does this pass without the critical review that you just gave? Is Light not aware of the shrinking of the industry? Im sure my former industry colleagues now selling real estate would love to have a word with him. This is beyond ridiculous.

Permalink to Comment

2. InfMP on August 9, 2012 11:48 AM writes...

Schooled.

Permalink to Comment

3. Ashley on August 9, 2012 11:57 AM writes...

What a wonderful article - thank you.
Perhaps these issues wouldn't be so dire if the citizens of this country would stop thoughtlessly and (to their way of thinking) effortlessy popping pills and start dedicating themselves to disease prevention and healthy living

That would only apply to some conditions, not Alzheimer's and cancer of course

Permalink to Comment

4. Ashley on August 9, 2012 11:58 AM writes...

What a wonderful article - thank you.
Perhaps these issues wouldn't be so dire if the citizens of this country would stop thoughtlessly and (to their way of thinking) effortlessy popping pills and start dedicating themselves to disease prevention and healthy living

That would only apply to some conditions, not Alzheimer's and cancer of course

Permalink to Comment

5. Twelve on August 9, 2012 12:11 PM writes...

The smug idiots who published that garbage will soon be forgotten, but your reply will live on. This apologia is luminous with clarity - it should be a mandatory reference for everyone who wants to understand the business/science tensions intrinsic to modern, high-stakes drug discovery.

Permalink to Comment

6. Experienced Drug Developer on August 9, 2012 12:15 PM writes...

Well told, Derek. Don't apologize for your anger and emotion - those of us who have done this for any period of time know you are right.

Permalink to Comment

7. Anonymous on August 9, 2012 12:20 PM writes...

Does anyone have an insight into Donald Lights' angle here? Most folks do the "there is no climate change" baiting when there is an agenda to reap financial benefits. Does he make that much from books and interviews, etc. to justify killing his professional reputation like this? Are there interest groups that would profit greatly to advance such provocative nonsense? What are they?

Permalink to Comment

8. Hap on August 9, 2012 12:39 PM writes...

1) Why should the authors taint a beautiful theory with facts and logic?

2) People fight harder for ideas, sometimes, than money. Both the (lowball, silly) drug cost estimate and this article probably have the agenda of trying to get the money to make drug costs (and other health care costs) from drug companies, and the argument is a way for them to rationalize that means to themselves. The mechanisms would also promote a more centralized system, with presumably the government having more power and businesses having less. For more selfish reasons, their arguments might get them political connections and power with certain people and groups, and perhaps money.

There's also the possibility that it's just the academic (in both senses) study of drug discovery. "Why are battles in academia so vicious? Because the stakes are so low."

Permalink to Comment

9. smurf on August 9, 2012 1:13 PM writes...

Thanks - your angry posts are often the best!

Permalink to Comment

10. noko marie on August 9, 2012 1:22 PM writes...

Rock on, man, rock on.

Permalink to Comment

11. Prof. Light on August 9, 2012 1:46 PM writes...

Damn it.

Permalink to Comment

12. qetzal on August 9, 2012 2:00 PM writes...

@#7

It gets him attention.

Permalink to Comment

13. Pig Farmer on August 9, 2012 2:30 PM writes...

"Without patents new drugs are immediately open to generic competition, lowering prices, while at the same time innovators are rewarded quickly to innovate again"
Er, no.... without patents no-one would bother to develop new drugs in the first place, since they would be unlikely ever to recoup their investment.
Looks like the lights are out chez Donald Light.

Permalink to Comment

14. Hap on August 9, 2012 2:40 PM writes...

12: Why doesn't he just get a reality show then and be done with it? The Jersey Shore's not far away - the culture clash between academia and the Shore ought to be hilarious enough to get MTV interested, right?

Permalink to Comment

15. Larry on August 9, 2012 3:10 PM writes...

Here's a kind word for prizes. They make sense when the big costs are upgront and marginal cost (e.g., cost per pill) are low, as they are for most drugs and if the prize is large enough to call out more research $, as would likely be the case for e.g., new antibiotics.

The prize would be used to purchase (and place in the public domain) the related patents. The size of the prize (and criteria for winning) would be announced in advance and the developer would have the option to not sell. Prizewinners could be manufactured and sold globally at everyday low prices.

Drugs that didn't win the prize would be marketed as the developer chooses, i.e., as they are today.

The X-Prize worked brilliantly both for space flight and for self-driving cars. Don't throw this beautiful baby out with the leftie bathwater!

Permalink to Comment

16. petros on August 9, 2012 3:18 PM writes...

I can see why this got you going Derek even though I can't read the full article

I can't see how a sociologist knows much about the problems of drug discovery (see http://www.med.upenn.edu/apps/faculty/index.php/g358/p31974)

Permalink to Comment

17. Patrick on August 9, 2012 3:29 PM writes...

@5 "The smug idiots who published that garbage will soon be forgotten, but your reply will live on."

I don't think it is a good idea to be so dismissive of them, not matter how wrong they are. They know the public is eager to hear the things they are telling them. Their views will be widely disseminated and parroted.

For example, the dubious claims made only a few days ago have already appeared in Wikipedia, one of the world's most widely read websites (http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Pharmaceutical_industry). It will stay there influencing, directly or indirectly, millions of people unless more knowledgeable people like Derek's readers step in to do something about it.

Permalink to Comment

18. Prometheus on August 9, 2012 4:20 PM writes...

@17 Wise words - whatever we think about the content, this will be in tune with the beliefs of many, possibly the majority of Doctors. I personally find it disturbing that The British Medical Journal sees fit to publish this but it says all we need to know about the reputation of the Industry.
Sadly, that reputation is for the main part self-inflicted - consider how this article might appear in the context of the recent 3 billion dollar GSK settlement.

Permalink to Comment

19. Phil on August 9, 2012 4:26 PM writes...

Derek,

Have you thought about responding to the article on the BMJ website?

http://www.bmj.com/content/345/bmj.e4348?tab=response-form

Permalink to Comment

20. anon2 on August 9, 2012 5:53 PM writes...

Preaching to the converted.

Permalink to Comment

21. Chemjobber on August 9, 2012 6:07 PM writes...

@Petros (#16):

Wow, what a find.

"As one of the founding fellows of the Center for Bioethics, Professor Light has continued exploring issues of distributive justice. He has tried to broaden the call for universal access to health care to involve conservatives and people of faith. Why, for example, do most conservatives in every other industrialized country support universal access while American conservatives do not? What Biblical texts speak to this issue?"

Headdesk.

Permalink to Comment

23. John on August 9, 2012 6:50 PM writes...

Always interesting to read articles written by people with a vested interest in a subject. There is a bit of missing the wood for the trees here. You can take down any argument point by point, using selected counter-narratives and claim victory.

The real question is:

Are the best health outcomes generated by (a) giving large amounts of money to centralized organizations such as pharma companies or univeristies to do research into drugs or by (b) giving the equivalent money to community health care to persue non-drug interventions?

This is the true test of the relevance of pharma (uni and corporate) as it exists today, and I would be interested to hear a less angry and more considered response to this.

Permalink to Comment

24. J. Galt on August 9, 2012 6:59 PM writes...

Lexchin and Light are neo-marxists. The wonderfully successful company once called Solyndra comes to mind. This top-down command economy approach is no more sustainable than the current industry model. They are simply replacing the current private sector MBA's with government officials.

Permalink to Comment

25. Andy on August 9, 2012 7:54 PM writes...

Look at a fabulously successful oncology drug: rituximab. In one indication registration trial Genentech enrolled 162 patients in the treatment arm and 160 patients in the standard-of-care arm for a total of 322 patients. We (not Genentech) ballpark that the costs to run a registration trial comes in around $150k per patient. That puts the cost of just getting the one registration study done at $48.3M, so in the ballpark of the $43M Lexchin/Light estimate. BUT, that assumes that all the other development costs (preclinical through phase 2) are zero, and it assumes that every drug is the total efficacy blockbuster that rituxan is, and it assumes that every drug that goes to a registration trial succeeds, clearly all fantasies of the highest order.

Permalink to Comment

26. dearieme on August 9, 2012 8:25 PM writes...

"Most folks do the "there is no climate change" baiting when there is an agenda to reap financial benefits": you got any evidence?

Permalink to Comment

27. matt on August 9, 2012 11:00 PM writes...

I agree with most everything you said, and agree the BMJ article writers seem to have missed the target.

Playing devil's advocate toward a slightly different target, however, there is less sympathy for high development costs the more one realizes how executives have placed exorbitant bets on horses lame in two legs. There was no excuse for gambling on Phase III for bapineuzumab, when Phase II missed its targets, and there were myriad ways to reduce the risk and firm up understanding of what was happening. None of that research would have cost as much as a Phase III (did Forbes say J&J was taking a $300-400 million writedown for that?!), and the Phase III contributed to almost none of the needed understanding. Similar bad gambling scorn could be directed at GSK and Sirtris, and has been, on these pages. And one wonders, do the billion dollar fines like GSK paid get charged as an advertising cost? If advertising still shows a profit, perhaps the fine needed to be higher.

None of this diminishes the hard work of the employees of these companies, who suffer and will pay the price for these bad bets. Tighten your belts, kids, looks like daddy spent all the income at the horse track again. (Or was it loose women offering the benefits of red wine?)

Not to ignore the chancy nature of even the best Phase III: there are certainly obscure side effects and interactions that can bite even when due diligence is done. That's all the more reason to do risk reduction, in the form of making sure your Phase II results are positive, of developing diagnostics to determine what effect your substance has (on both sides of the BBB for CNS targets, maybe for multiple forms of the substance if they exist), or in the absence of the latter putting further trials on hold until more post-mortem analyses come in. Flying blind worked in the past; it appears it is not paying off now.

It seems clear that executive compensation in the pharma industry needs adjustment. Just as in banking, there need to be clawback provisions on executive pay and bonuses, certainly (at a minimum) in the case of large fines like the recent GSK case. Put the whistleblower report chain directly in their inbox, and yank back pay and bonuses for up to ten years after they've left if legal shenanigans get charged to their watch.

That way, when Andrew Witty is saying "Whilst these originate in a different era for the company, they cannot and will not be ignored," someone can ask whether he has clawed back some of the executive pay that rewarded the misbehavior and if not, why not. At the very minimum, investors should demand this. Certainly GSK wouldn't cover the cost of the fine, but in truth the fine wouldn't need to be nearly as large if the executives responsible were actually getting punished. In Cold War terms, the more accurate the placement, the smaller the warhead needs to be. Less collateral damage is a huge bonus.

Permalink to Comment

28. MoMo on August 9, 2012 11:06 PM writes...

Do you think Light is eligible now for an IgNoble award? Wait! Those are for real articles!

Permalink to Comment

29. Barry Bunin on August 10, 2012 12:06 AM writes...

This has got to be the funniest, passionate rant on In The Pipeline to date. Obviously struck a nerve. I was laughing and thinking. Of course public markets are efficient. With the fall of the USSR, we all thought capitalism certainly trumped communism. Now China is showing some coordination can be efficient and effective.

It is interesting to think about what would be most efficient in terms of absolute separated competition and absolute open coordination in the drug discovery space. Perhaps there are areas where groups can compete and collaborate at the same time. Targets and ideas are a dime a dozen, how much is insight vs timing vs execution to get to market with a winner. What is the optimal balance between which areas can be pre-competitive while others remain competitive?

Neglected diseases would be one area for experimentation with models.

Permalink to Comment

30. Adam Jacobs on August 10, 2012 1:49 AM writes...

Wow, I am in awe. I don't think I've ever read such a thorough and well argued take-down of any article published in the BMJ (or maybe anywhere!) before.

There is one point, however, I think you haven't mentioned, which is highly pertinent here. I am very concerned about the effects of over-regulation on pharmaceutical development costs. Clinical trials are unbelievably heavily regulated: we can barely sneeze without having to follow an SOP for it and filling in a form to say which direction we sneezed in and signing it in triplicate.

While I appreciate the motivations behind regulation of the pharmaceutical industry are entirely well-meaning and designed to promote patient safety, I cannot believe that the current status of regulation is anywhere near cost effective. In fact I recently went to a talk given by a regulator about a particular new regulation, and I asked him in the Q&A session whether any cost-benefit analysis of the regulation had been done. He looked surprised by the question and said that it hadn't.

It is certainly a problem that the costs of clinical development have been rising inexorably, and I suspect over-regulation is a huge part of that. We really need a more imaginative way of ensuring patient safety without the multi-billion pound price tag that the current system has. I'm not necessarily suggesting we do away with regulation altogether (although that could actually be worth considering, if coupled with something like unlimited personal liability for pharma company executives if patients are harmed in a reasonably-preventable manner) but I really do think the current system is way too complex and not fit for purpose.

Permalink to Comment

31. Billy on August 10, 2012 4:49 AM writes...

I don't want to comment on the content of Light and Lexchin's article, or your considered reply Derek. Just one point which as a research scientist and publisher in peer reviewed journals should tell you this house of cards never ought to have been built - the references.

Several of the key references to the authors arguaments come from their own literature - I said this in the past so it must be true! The one that really grabs me though and means the paper it is printed on will soon be making it's way to the trash can...

"The 1.3% of revenues devoted to discovering new molecules (Ref 23) compares with the 25% that an independent analysis estimates is spent on promotion,(Ref 35)..."

This "independant analysis - reference 35" is written by (of course) Joel Lexchin - one of the authors claiming it to be independant!

I rest my case, and the paper plane is well on its way.

Permalink to Comment

32. MK on August 10, 2012 7:02 AM writes...

@23: what do you mean by non-drug interventions? Reiki, voodoo or urinotherapy?

Permalink to Comment

33. MK on August 10, 2012 7:17 AM writes...

@24: This sounds marxist indeed. It may sound odd and inappropriate on this forum, but (as I come from a post-communist country, so I know what I'm talking about) I think that such anti-capitalist (i.e. communist) views should not be tolerated and their proponents should be ostracised just like neonazis are.

Permalink to Comment

34. JOhn on August 10, 2012 8:07 AM writes...

MK, there are non-drug interventions and it doesn't take much imagination to think of them. Lifestyle factors play a major role in health. Pharma thrives on the mentality that there is a drug that can cure us from adverse lifestyles which are now classified as "disorders". Lipitor anyone?

Permalink to Comment

35. Anonymous on August 10, 2012 8:17 AM writes...

@30 "I cannot believe that the current status of regulation is anywhere near cost effective. In fact I recently went to a talk given by a regulator about a particular new regulation, and I asked him in the Q&A session whether any cost-benefit analysis of the regulation had been done. He looked surprised by the question and said that it hadn't."

Actually, cost-benefit analysis is a routine and generally required (http://exchange.regulations.gov/exchange/sites/default/files/doc_files/President's%20Executive%20Order%2013563_0.pdf) part of the regulation development process. When FDA publishes a new regulation in the Federal Register, you can find the cost-benefit analysis in the preamable to the regulation.

Permalink to Comment

36. lJStewartTweet on August 10, 2012 8:21 AM writes...

Thank you Derek!

Permalink to Comment

37. rob on August 10, 2012 8:27 AM writes...

He has put the BMJ paper on his webiste: http://www.pharmamyths.net/files/BMJ-Innova_ARTICLE_8-11-12.pdf

Permalink to Comment

38. Adam Jacobs on August 10, 2012 9:27 AM writes...

@35

This was a European regulation, so maybe we do things differently on different sides of the pond.

It's interesting to see that the FDA does them. I would be amazed if they are done in a sensible way and they still find the regulations are cost effective.

Permalink to Comment

39. petros on August 10, 2012 9:44 AM writes...

Rob (#37) thanks for that info

Only 7 of the 41 references by at least one of the authors!

They suggest new drugs should only be approved on the basis of hard clinical outcomes or superiority to a comparator rather than non-inferiority to a comparator or superiority over placebo.

That approach would result in very few new drugs being approved at all!

Permalink to Comment

40. Stewie G. on August 10, 2012 10:48 AM writes...

Derek, I'm sure you would feel differently if you heard these chaps read their paper aloud. Once you hear their accent and diction you'll understand that they are hopelessly smarter than the rest of us. And you, from Arkansas, Puhleease.

Permalink to Comment

41. John Wayne on August 10, 2012 11:07 AM writes...

This sort of thing really gets me annoyed.

Are there waste and dumb decisions in pharma? You bet. How about waste and dumb decisions in government? Sure, tons. Which is better? Wiser? Which will lead to better outcomes?

I don't know, but the waste in companies both happens faster and (surprisingly) has more accountability. So, from my perspective, pharma is the lesser of two evils. It is reasonable to believe that the opposite is true, but it is not reasonable to infer that you are completely right and the others are completely wrong.

Did anybody call the other side a Nazi yet? It's not a debate until somebody uses the N-word (2000's version).

Permalink to Comment

42. Anonymous on August 10, 2012 11:31 AM writes...

@John Wayne
I've been wondering for some time if a private company is the best way to do early research. It seems to me that the focus on quarterly profits would be counterproductive to science. I fear that this might get worse as the 'easier' targets have been hit. The more difficult targets may prove to take to long to develop for. How many quarters can a private company justify continuing research into a particular area without actually getting a drug out. I've often wondered if development times have dramatically increased and if so what impact this will have on pharmas profitability and productivity going forward. Will investors be willing to give companies enough time to develop drugs successfully? Particularly given the trend towards drugs with smaller markets. If the age of personalized medicine ever does arrive how will continuing drug development remain profitable as markets fragment?

Permalink to Comment

43. Anonymous on August 10, 2012 11:32 AM writes...

@John Wayne
I've been wondering for some time if a private company is the best way to do early research. It seems to me that the focus on quarterly profits would be counterproductive to science. I fear that this might get worse as the 'easier' targets have been hit. The more difficult targets may prove to take to long to develop for. How many quarters can a private company justify continuing research into a particular area without actually getting a drug out. I've often wondered if development times have dramatically increased and if so what impact this will have on pharmas profitability and productivity going forward. Will investors be willing to give companies enough time to develop drugs successfully? Particularly given the trend towards drugs with smaller markets. If the age of personalized medicine ever does arrive how will continuing drug development remain profitable as markets fragment?

Permalink to Comment

44. Bunsen Honeydew on August 10, 2012 12:22 PM writes...

Derek, I love it when you get emotional. It's entertaining and still spot on!

We have had serious discussions on here about the struggles of peer review and I think this is an example of it failing in an phenomenal way.

Permalink to Comment

45. John Wayne on August 10, 2012 12:29 PM writes...

@42 Anonymous

There are some big negatives on both sides of the equation in pharma and academia.

Pharma tends to focus on 'low hanging fruit' biochemical targets with large potential returns. They get confused when (1) the target doesn't derive hits from HTS, (2) it doesn't work in vivo (or in humans), and (3) the space is crowded with every company you have heard of (and several that you haven't) because everybody reads the same papers for their target 'ideas.' Next, the quarter (or year) comes to an end and you need to somehow tell a divisional vice president that the team succeeded. This leads to zombie programs that should die, inept 'me too' targeting to fill up the basic research pipeline, and ill advised progression if compounds with dubious profiles to the clinic (Lily gets the King Idiot prize for this one for their a beta compound that doesn't get into the brain - good control compound; high risk drug for AD).

On the academic side most PI's try to push on diseases and indications neglected by pharma but not neglected by various funding agencies. They pretend that big pharma is doing it wrong, and they will cause a paradigm shift in medicinal chemistry. This is a great goal.
Unfortunately, medicinal chemistry is not a list of positive things to do to make drugs, but rather a list of common pitfalls that academics are in the process of wasting years rediscovering.
(1) HTS: go ahead and check contemporary literature for papers about the pitfalls of HTS; you will be amused. This stuff was noted in the 90's, but you can always rewrite that paper about avoiding thioureas if you make up a cool new acronym. (Sidebar: micromolar inhibitors of biochemical assays with poor Hill slopes aren't really hits, they are assay artifacts: stop publishing this crap.)
(2) ADME: Some PI's are sophisticated enough to get microsomal data on some compounds; these folks are ahead of the pack. Stay tuned for 'new' papers on how microsomal stability is not really that great a predictor of whole animal PK.
(3) While the industrial folks tend to kill projects early (or after the year end reviews; whichever causes fewer layoffs), academics never ever kill anything. There are scores of protein-protein interaction projects eating grad students and postdocs as we speak.

My experience doing drug discovery in pharma and academia have revealed some potential issues. Right now I am trying biotech, and I'll keep my ear to the ground for the best place to do basic research.

Permalink to Comment

46. drug_hunter on August 10, 2012 3:18 PM writes...

John @23 - John suggests that somehow Derek is playing a game by merely revealing "point by point" the utter vacuousness of the Lexchin article, and that Derek is thereby missing the forest for the trees. And that, somehow, this is all because Derek has a particular axe to grind. What utter nonsense. There is no forest left standing - it is an intellectual wasteland. It would appear that for some reason John is attempting to shift our attention away from the fact that the Lexchin article is COMPLETELY WRONG and is HIGHLY DAMAGING for the many reasons raised by Derek and some of the other posters.

John then goes on to ask a good question about what are the most cost-effective ways to achieve the best health outcomes, but of course that is a fundamentally DIFFERENT topic than whether there is a scrap of validity in Lexchin's argument (hint: there isn't).

Always sad to see polemics and sloppy logic in the comments on this blog - brings down the curve. But I guess any group needs a bottom decile.

Permalink to Comment

47. Nick K on August 10, 2012 9:03 PM writes...

http://www.guardian.co.uk/commentisfree/2012/aug/10/profit-pr-enemies-innovation

As predicted by an earlier poster, Light and Lexchin's idiotic article has already been picked up by the mainstream media.

Permalink to Comment

48. Ragnar on August 10, 2012 10:40 PM writes...

Derek, this is your best post ever. If you haven't read Atlas Shrugged yet, now you're ready for it.

Permalink to Comment

49. MIMD on August 11, 2012 1:27 AM writes...

Enough. I should mention that when Prof. Light's earlier figure for drug expense came out that I had a brief correspondence with him, and I invited him to come to this site and try out his reasoning on people who develop drugs for a living.

Brilliant. The acid test of true conviction.

Permalink to Comment

50. MIMD on August 11, 2012 1:32 AM writes...

@46

This site is a great relatively concise resource on logical fallacy: http://www.nizkor.org/features/fallacies/

The Mother of all such sites is at http://www.fallacyfiles.org/taxonomy.html

Permalink to Comment

51. Castalia on August 11, 2012 4:18 AM writes...

The problem with the public perception of our Industry can be encapsulated as:

Q. Who benefits from Drug Discovery continuing to be "massively expensive, lengthy and seldom successful"?

A. Us.


Permalink to Comment

52. matt on August 11, 2012 7:56 AM writes...

@50 Castalia:

How so? I don't see the benefits for anybody. And the public doesn't think of the drug discovery process as expensive, they think it is trivial and cheap and quick; therefore they think drug prices are pure profit. Hence this blog entry in response to an ignorant article published in a prominent place stating exactly that premise.

Permalink to Comment

53. scott pollard on August 11, 2012 10:09 AM writes...

We get so thick into things that it's very difficult to maintain a perspective. Check out Ivan Illich and his talk about the "medical industrial complex" in "Medical Nemesis". Check out Sarah Knox and her insights in "Science, God and the Nature of Reality: Bias in Biomedical Research". It's all there. The BMJ article and this response are both directed at the wrong target or barking up the wrong tree.

Permalink to Comment

54. scott pollard on August 11, 2012 10:12 AM writes...

We get so thick into things that it's very difficult to maintain a perspective. Check out Ivan Illich and his talk about the "medical industrial complex" in "Medical Nemesis". Check out Sarah Knox and her insights in "Science, God and the Nature of Reality: Bias in Biomedical Research". It's all there. The BMJ article and this response are both directed at the wrong target or barking up the wrong tree.

Permalink to Comment

55. metaphysician on August 11, 2012 10:50 AM writes...

Re: 48-

Good lord, hit the deck everyone. The Objectivists are out to save our souls. . .

Permalink to Comment

56. Castalia on August 11, 2012 11:20 AM writes...

@51 matt:

It certainly feels like all sides in the debate could benefit from transparent, independently verified data. As only the Industry knows the individual cost of discovering and developing each of its (successfully approved) drugs, then we must wait for a principled CEO to break ranks and release those numbers.

Clearly, those figures must only be valid in the context of the cost of all the simultaneously unsuccessful programmes but does, say $43 million dollars seem unreasonable for finding and taking a small molecule to approval?

Until that day, all we've got is the likes of JP Garnier (The Guardian, 30 July 2005):
"It is easier to put a rocket on the moon than to discover a new drug, and it also costs less money."

Really?


Permalink to Comment

57. J Severs on August 11, 2012 3:27 PM writes...

That is what I call heavy shelling. Well done.

Permalink to Comment

58. Johannes on August 11, 2012 4:45 PM writes...

""Meanwhile, telling "innovation crisis" stories to politicians and the press serves as a ploy, a strategy to attract a range of government protections from free market, generic competition."

"protections from free market, generic competition"

"Generic competition"

Does he even know it's not the production cost you pay for in a pill? lol

Permalink to Comment

59. Johannes on August 11, 2012 4:46 PM writes...

""Meanwhile, telling "innovation crisis" stories to politicians and the press serves as a ploy, a strategy to attract a range of government protections from free market, generic competition."

"protections from free market, generic competition"

"Generic competition"

Does he even know it's not the production cost you pay for in a pill? lol. He just lost all credibility for me in that line

Permalink to Comment

60. Hail Stalin on August 11, 2012 4:53 PM writes...

lmao, look at this fascist pig who wants to bleed the common man to pay his own salary. Seriously, you have a poisoned brain, capitalist running dog.

Permalink to Comment

61. metaphysician on August 12, 2012 8:47 AM writes...

And now we've got an unrepentant communist ( or a troll pretending to be one ). Any chance the objectivists and communists could go shoot each other?

And no, I don't believe 43 million to bring a drug to market. Not even a little bit. Stage III alone can cost that much.

Permalink to Comment

62. Prof Donald Light on August 12, 2012 7:15 PM writes...


It's hard to respond to so many sarcastic and baiting trashings by Dr. Lowe and some of his fan club, but let me try. I wonder if Dr. Lowe allows his followers to read what I write here without cutting and editing.

First, let me clarify some of the mis-representations about the new BMJ article that claims the innovation crisis is a myth. While the pharmaceutical industry and its global network of journalists have been writing that the industry has been in real trouble because innovation has been dropping, all those articles and figures are based on the decline of new molecules approved since a sharp spike. FDA figures make it clear that the so-called crisis has been simply a return to the long-term average. In fact, in recent years, companies have been getting above-average approvals for new molecules. Is there any reasonably argument with these FDA figures? I see none from Dr. Lowe or in the 15 pages of comments.

Second, the reported costs of R&D have been rising sharply, and we do not go into these; but here are a couple of points. We note that the big picture – total additional investments in R&D (which are self-reported from closely held figures) over the past 15 years were matched by six times greater increase in revenues. We can all guess various reasons why, but surely a 6-fold return is not a crisis or “unsustainable.” In fact, it’s evidence that companies know what they are doing.

Another point from international observers is that the costs of clinical trials in the U.S. are much higher than in equally affluent countries and much higher than they need to be, because everyone seems to make money the higher they are in the U.S. market. I have not looked into this but I think it would be interesting to see in what ways costly clinical trials are a boon for several of the stakeholders.

Third, regarding that infamously low cost of R&D that Dr. Lowe and readers like to slam, consider this: The low estimate is based on the same costs of R&D reported by companies (which are self-reported from closely held figures) to their leading policy research center as were used to estimate the average cost is $1.3 bn (and soon to be raised again). Doesn’t that make you curious enough to want to find out how we show what inflators were used to ramp the reported costs up, which use to do the same in reverse? Would it be unfair to ask you to actually read how we took this inflationary estimate apart? Or is it easier just to say our estimate is “idiotic” and “absurd”? How about reading the whole argument at www.pharmamyths.net and then discuss its merits?

Our estimate is for net, median corporate cost of D(evelopment) for that same of drugs from the 1990s that the health economists supported by the industry used to ramp up the high estimate. Net, because taxpayer subsidies which the industry has fought hard to expand pay for about 44% of gross R&D costs. Median, because a few costly cases which are always featured raise the average artificially. Corporate, because a lot of R(eseach) and some D is paid for by others – governments, foundations, institutes. We don’t include an estimate for R(eseach) because no one knows what it is and it varies so much from a chance discovery that costs almost nothing to years and decades of research, failures, dead ends, new angles, before finally an effective drug is discovered.

So it’s an unknown and highly variable R plus more knowable estimate of net, median, corporate costs. Even then, companies never so show their books, and they never compare their costs of R&D to revenues and profits. They just keep telling us their unverifiable costs of R&D are astronomical.

We make clear that neither we nor anyone else knows either the average gross cost or the net, median costs of R&D because major companies have made sure we cannot. Further, the “average cost of R&D” estimate began in 1976 as a lobbying strategy to come up with an artificial number that could be used to wow Congressmen. It’s worked wonderfully, mythic as it may be.

Current layoffs need to be considered (as do most things) from a 10-year perspective. A lot industry observers have commented on companies being “bloated” and adding too many hires. Besides trimming back to earlier numbers, the big companies increasingly realize (it has taken them years) that it’s smarter to let thousands of biotechs and research teams try to find good new drugs, rather than doing it in-house. To regard those layoffs as an abandonment of research misconstrues the corporate strategies.


Fourth, we never use “me-too.” We speak of minor variations, and we say it’s clinically valuable to have 3-4 in a given therapeutic class, but marginal gains fall quite low after that.


Fifth, our main point about innovation is that current criteria for approval and incentives strongly reward companies doing exactly what they are doing, developing scores of minor variations to fill their sales lines and market for good profits. We don’t see any conspiracy here, only rational economic behavior by smart businessmen.

But while all new drug products are better than placebo or not too worse than a comparator, often against surrogate end points, most of those prove to be little better than last year’s “better” drugs, or the years before… You can read detailed assessments by independent teams at several sites. Of course companies are delighted when new drugs are really better against clinical outcomes; but meantime we cite evidence that 80 percent of additional pharmaceutical costs go to buying newly patented minor variations. The rewards to do anything to get another cancer drug approved are so great that independent reviewers find few of them help patients much, and the area is corrupted by conflict-of-interest marketing.

So we conclude there is a “hidden business model” behind the much touted business model, to spend billions on R&D to discover breakthrough drugs that greatly improve health and works fine until the “patent cliff” sends the company crashing to the canyon floor. The heroic tale is true to some extent and sometimes; but the hidden business model is to develop minor variations and make solid profits from them. That sounds like rational economic behavior to me.
The trouble is, all these drugs are under-tested for risks of harm, and all drugs are toxic to one degree or another. My book, The Risks of Prescription Drugs, assembles evidence that there is an epidemic of harmful side effects, largely from hundreds of drugs with few or no advantages to offset their risks of harm.

Is that what we want? My neighbors want clinically better drugs. They think the FDA approves clinically better drugs and don’t realize that’s far from the case. Most folks think “innovation” means clinically superior, but it doesn’t. Most new molecules do not prove to be clinically superior. The term “innovation” is used vaguely to signal better drugs for patients; but while many new drugs are technically innovative, they do not help patients much. The false rhetoric of “innovative” and “innovation” needs to be replaced by what we want and mean: “clinically superior drugs.”


If we want clinically better drugs, why don’t we ask for them and pay according to added value – no more if no better and a lot more if substantially better? Instead, standards for testing effectiveness and risk of harms is being lowered, and – guess what – that will reward still more minor variations by rational economic executives, not more truly superior “innovative” drugs.

I hope you find some of these points worthwhile and interesting. I’m trying to reply to 20 single-space pages of largely inaccurate criticism, often with no reasoned explanation for a given slur or dismissal. I hope we can do better than that. I thought the comments by Matt #27 and John Wayne #45 were particularly interesting.

Donald W. Light


Permalink to Comment

63. Anon on August 13, 2012 1:08 AM writes...

Re: I wonder if Dr. Lowe allows his followers to read what I write here without cutting and editing.

Yes, he does; perhaps it says something about your personality, sir, that you would think not.

Permalink to Comment

64. DrSnowboard on August 13, 2012 1:56 AM writes...

My feeling is that post from Prof Light is actually quite useful in explaining the paper's view, even if you disagree with the 'politics'. Personally, I find it funny that there's this rallying to the capitalist high ground when previously we've be